Mutualisms: cooperation between species: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
|||
Line 71: | Line 71: | ||
=== Dynamical domains === | === Dynamical domains === | ||
In spatial settings the formation of clusters reduces exploitation and increases interactions with other cooperators to make up for losses against defectors. Spatial assortment enables co-existence. | In spatial settings the formation of clusters reduces exploitation and increases interactions with other cooperators to make up for losses against defectors. Spatial assortment enables co-existence. This results in four dynamical domains depending on the cost-to-benefit ratio of cooperation, | ||
# | # | ||
Line 77: | Line 77: | ||
# | # | ||
# | # | ||
The four dynamical regimes are separated by three different types of [[#Critical phase transitions|critical phase transitions]]. | |||
Line 104: | Line 106: | ||
==== [[EvoLudoLab: Mutualisms - Bursts of defection|Bursts of defection]]==== | ==== [[EvoLudoLab: Mutualisms - Bursts of defection|Bursts of defection]]==== | ||
[[Image:Mutualism - asymmetric bursts.png| | [[Image:Mutualism - asymmetric bursts.png|820px|link= EvoLudoLab: Mutualisms - Bursts of defection]] | ||
Snapshots '''a'''-'''d''' illustrate the spatial distribution of the four strategy pairs between lattices, | Snapshots '''a'''-'''d''' illustrate the spatial distribution of the four strategy pairs between lattices, |
Revision as of 15:21, 9 August 2024
In mutualistic associations two species cooperate by exchanging goods or services with members of another species for their mutual benefit. At the same time competition for reproduction primarily continues with members of their own species. In intra-species interactions the prisoner's dilemma is the leading mathematical metaphor to study the evolution of cooperation. Here we consider inter-species interactions in the spatial prisoner's dilemma, where members of each species reside on one lattice layer. Cooperators provide benefits to neighbouring members of the other species at a cost to themselves. Hence, interactions occur across layers but competition remains within layers. We show that rich and complex dynamics unfold when varying the cost-to-benefit ratio of cooperation,
The problem of cooperation
The evolution and maintenance of cooperation ranks among the most fundamental questions in biological, social and economical systems. Cooperators provide benefits to others at a cost to themselves. Cooperation is a conundrum because on the one hand everyone benefits from mutual cooperation but on the other hand individuals face the temptation to increase their personal gains by defecting and withholding cooperation. This generates a conflict of interest between the group and the individual, which is termed a social dilemma. The prisoner's dilemma is the most popular mathematical metaphor of a social dilemma and theoretical tool to study cooperation through evolutionary game theory.
Donation game
In the simplest and most intuitive instance of the prisoner's dilemma, the donation game, two players meet and decide whether to cooperate and provide a benefit
Thus, both players prefer mutual cooperation over mutual defection, yet defection yields the higher payoff regardless of what the partner does and hence the conflict of interest arises.
The problem of cooperation is exacerbated for actions that bestow benefits not just to other individuals but to those of another species. In particular it is crucial to clearly distinguish between the acts of cooperation of an individual and mutualistic interactions between individuals. Accomplishing mutually beneficial interactions requires coordination of cooperative acts between species.
Here we focus on the simplest setup with two identical species of equal population size each following the same ecological and evolutionary updating process.
Well-mixed populations
In intra-species interactions with random interactions, a so-called well-mixed population, the payoffs to cooperators and defectors soleley depends on their frequencies. In this case the replicator equation describes the change in the frequency of cooperators,
where
In inter-species interactions it is of crucial importance to distinguish between cooperation -- costly acts of individuals that benefit others -- and mutualistic interactions, where both parties benefit from the interaction. For the inter-species donation game cooperators of one species,
where
Eq.
For simplicity we assume that species
where
Spatial populations

In order to delineate effects of spatial dimensions on cooperation in mutualistic interactions, we consider two parallel, square lattice layers with
Dynamical domains
In spatial settings the formation of clusters reduces exploitation and increases interactions with other cooperators to make up for losses against defectors. Spatial assortment enables co-existence. This results in four dynamical domains depending on the cost-to-benefit ratio of cooperation,
: defection dominates. For high costs or low benefits, spatial correlations are insufficient to support cooperation and both populations evolve towards the absorbing state. The outcome is the same as in well-mixed populations, see . : cooperators and defectors co-exist. The frequency of cooperators in the dynamical equilibrium is equal in both layers and increases for decreasing . : spontaneous symmetry breaking. Cooperators and defectors continue to co-exist in a dynamical equilibrium but with essentially complementary strategy frequencies in the two layers. : relaxation into asymmetric absorbing states or . The emergence, growth and elimination of homogeneous domains of defection ( regions) drive spikes (or bursts) in defector frequencies.
The four dynamical regimes are separated by three different types of critical phase transitions.
Symmetric cooperation: random walk
The spatial configuration of cooperators,
The spatial configuration of cooperators,
Asymmetric cooperation
Typical spatial strategy distribution in the asymmetric phase with essentially complementary frequencies and distributions of cooperators and defectors in the two layers. Parameters are the same as in the previous figures but with
Bursts of defection
Snapshots a-d illustrate the spatial distribution of the four strategy pairs between lattices,
First, small islands of
Critical phase transitions
Directed percolation
Spontaneous symmetry breaking
Bursts of defection
References
- Hauert, C. & Szabó, G. (2024) Spontaneous symmetry breaking of cooperation between species, PNAS Nexus (in print)